Daniel Susskind: 3 myths about the future of work (and why they're not true)
Daniel Susskind explores the impact of technology, particularly artificial intelligence, on work and society. Full bio
Double-click the English transcript below to play the video.
has been spreading lately,
that are unfolding
there will be significant change.
is what that change will look like.
is both troubling and exciting.
unemployment is real,
how I came to that conclusion,
our vision of this automated future.
on our television screens,
descends on the workplace
human beings from particular tasks,
substitute for human beings.
and more important.
human beings directly,
or more efficient at a particular task.
to navigate on unfamiliar roads.
computer-assisted design software
more complicated buildings.
just complement human beings directly.
and it does this in two ways.
of the economy as a pie,
makes the pie bigger.
incomes rise and demand grows.
the size it was 300 years ago.
from tasks in the old pie
in the new pie instead.
doesn't just make the pie bigger.
the ingredients in the pie.
their income in different ways,
across existing goods,
for entirely new goods, too.
new roles have to be filled.
most people worked on farms,
from tasks in the old bit of pie
in the new bit of pie instead.
complementarities,
to capture the different way
helps human beings.
two forces at play:
that harms workers,
that do the opposite.
making a medical diagnosis
at a fleeting glimpse have in common?
that until very recently,
couldn't readily be automated.
can be automated.
have driverless car programs.
that can diagnose medical problems.
that can identify a bird
on the part of economists.
they were wrong is very important.
have to copy the way
were trying to figure out
to automate a task
how it was they performed a task,
for a machine to follow.
intelligence at one point, too.
on artificial intelligence and the law
commercially available
a cool screen design at the time.
in the form of two floppy disks,
genuinely were floppy,
as the economists':
how it was she solved a legal problem,
in a set of rules for a machine to follow.
could explain themselves in this way,
and they could be automated.
can't explain themselves,
and they're thought to be out reach.
distinction is widespread.
that are predictable or repetitive,
different words for routine.
that I mentioned at the start.
of nonroutine tasks.
how she makes a medical diagnosis,
to give you a few rules of thumb,
creativity and judgment and intuition.
very difficult to articulate,
would be very hard to automate.
in writing a set of instructions
it's simply going to be wrong.
in data storage capability
routine-nonroutine distinction
of making a medical diagnosis.
announced they'd developed a system
whether or not a freckle is cancerous
or the intuition of a doctor.
nothing about medicine at all.
a pattern recognition algorithm
between those cases
in an unhuman way,
of more possible cases
to review in their lifetime.
how she'd performed the task.
who dwell upon that the fact
aren't built in our image.
on the US quiz show "Jeopardy!" in 2011,
human champions at "Jeopardy!"
by the philosopher John Searle
Doesn't Know It Won on 'Jeopardy!'"
let out a cry of excitement.
to say what a good job it had done.
that those human contestants played,
about human intelligence,
on automation than it was in the past.
perform tasks differently to human beings,
are currently capable of doing
might be capable of doing in the future.
of technological progress,
known as the lump of labor fallacy.
the lump of labor fallacy
of labor fallacy fallacy,
is a very old idea.
who gave it this name in 1892.
to come across a dock worker
a machine to make washers,
that fasten on the end of screws.
felt guilty for being more productive.
we expect the opposite,
for being unproductive,
on Facebook or Twitter at work.
for being more productive,
"I know I'm doing wrong.
some fixed lump of work
this machine to do more,
and became more productive,
demand for washers would rise,
for his pals to do.
"the lump of labor fallacy."
about the lump of labor fallacy
of all types of work.
out there to be divided up
making the original lump of work smaller,
gets bigger and changes.
that technological progress
New tasks have to be done.
to perform those tasks.
might get bigger and change,
the extra lump of work themselves.
rather than complement human beings,
to the task of driving a car.
directly complement human beings.
human beings better drivers.
human beings from the driving seat,
rather than complement human beings,
driverless cars more efficient,
that I mentioned as well.
will fall on goods that machines,
are best placed to produce.
to do the new tasks that have to be done.
isn't demand for human labor.
in all these complemented tasks,
that becomes less likely.
upon this balance between two forces:
that harms workers
that do the opposite.
has fallen in favor of human beings.
machine substitution,
of tasks performed by human beings.
are currently capable of
to draw to a polite stop
winds of complementarity
of task encroachment
the force of machine substitution,
those helpful complementarities too.
of that troubling future.
on tasks performed by human beings,
of machine substitution,
of machine complementarity.
falls in favor of machines
because I don't think we're there yet,
that this is our direction of travel.
this is a good problem to have.
one economic problem has dominated:
large enough for everyone to live on.
of the first century AD,
for everyone in the world,
on or around the poverty line.
economic growth has taken off.
slices of the pie today,
at two percent,
at a more measly one percent,
will be twice as rich as us.
that traditional economic problem.
if it does happen,
a symptom of that success,
how to make the pie bigger --
that everyone gets a slice.
solving this problem won't be easy.
at the economic dinner table,
or even without work,
how they get their slice.
of discussion, for instance,
of universal basic income
and in Finland and in Kenya.
that's right in front of us,
generated by our economic system
our traditional mechanism
us to think in very different ways.
about what ought to be done,
that this is a far better problem to have
our ancestors for centuries:
big enough in the first place.
ABOUT THE SPEAKER
Daniel Susskind - EconomistDaniel Susskind explores the impact of technology, particularly artificial intelligence, on work and society.
Why you should listen
Daniel Susskind is the co-author, with Richard Susskind, of the best-selling book, The Future of the Professions, and a Fellow in Economics at Balliol College, Oxford University. He is currently finishing his latest book, on the future of work. Previously, he worked in the British Government -- as a policy adviser in the Prime Minister's Strategy Unit, as a policy analyst in the Policy Unit in 10 Downing Street, and as a senior policy adviser in the Cabinet Office. Susskind received a doctorate in economics from Oxford University and was a Kennedy Scholar at Harvard University.
Daniel Susskind | Speaker | TED.com