ABOUT THE SPEAKER
Thomas Piketty - Economist
Thomas Piketty is an economist and professor at the Paris School of Economics. His 2014 book, "Capital in the Twenty-first Century," caused a sensation upon publication.

Why you should listen
Is the global economy accelerating toward a future that’s incompatible with democracy? In this provocative talk about inequality and wealth, economist Thomas Piketty provides new context for his groundbreaking book, Capital in the Twenty-First Century.
More profile about the speaker
Thomas Piketty | Speaker | TED.com
TEDSalon Berlin 2014

Thomas Piketty: New thoughts on capital in the twenty-first century

Filmed:
1,557,059 views

French economist Thomas Piketty caused a sensation in early 2014 with his book on a simple, brutal formula explaining economic inequality: r > g (meaning that return on capital is generally higher than economic growth). Here, he talks through the massive data set that led him to conclude: Economic inequality is not new, but it is getting worse, with radical possible impacts.
- Economist
Thomas Piketty is an economist and professor at the Paris School of Economics. His 2014 book, "Capital in the Twenty-first Century," caused a sensation upon publication. Full bio

Double-click the English transcript below to play the video.

00:12
It's very nice to be here tonight.
0
915
1965
00:14
So I've been working on the history of income
1
2880
3716
00:18
and wealth distribution for the past 15 years,
2
6596
3319
00:21
and one of the interesting lessons
3
9915
3101
00:25
coming from this historical evidence
4
13016
2501
00:27
is indeed that, in the long run,
5
15517
2013
00:29
there is a tendency for
the rate of return of capital
6
17530
3720
00:33
to exceed the economy's growth rate,
7
21250
2670
00:35
and this tends to lead to
high concentration of wealth.
8
23920
2745
00:38
Not infinite concentration of wealth,
9
26665
1833
00:40
but the higher the gap between r and g,
10
28498
2791
00:43
the higher the level of inequality of wealth
11
31289
2935
00:46
towards which society tends to converge.
12
34224
3207
00:49
So this is a key force that
I'm going to talk about today,
13
37431
3554
00:52
but let me say right away
14
40985
1969
00:54
that this is not the only important force
15
42954
2330
00:57
in the dynamics of income
and wealth distribution,
16
45284
2473
00:59
and there are many other forces that play
17
47757
2025
01:01
an important role in the long-run dynamics
18
49782
2981
01:04
of income and wealth distribution.
19
52763
1575
01:06
Also there is a lot of data
20
54338
1969
01:08
that still needs to be collected.
21
56307
1556
01:09
We know a little bit more today
22
57863
2932
01:12
than we used to know,
but we still know too little,
23
60795
2521
01:15
and certainly there are
many different processes —
24
63316
2676
01:17
economic, social, political —
25
65992
2298
01:20
that need to be studied more.
26
68290
1427
01:21
And so I'm going to focus today on this simple force,
27
69717
2980
01:24
but that doesn't mean that other important forces
28
72697
2261
01:26
do not exist.
29
74958
1204
01:28
So most of the data I'm going to present
30
76162
2272
01:30
comes from this database
31
78434
2205
01:32
that's available online:
32
80639
1260
01:33
the World Top Incomes Database.
33
81899
1485
01:35
So this is the largest existing
34
83384
2103
01:37
historical database on inequality,
35
85487
2453
01:39
and this comes from the effort
36
87940
1350
01:41
of over 30 scholars from several dozen countries.
37
89290
3892
01:45
So let me show you a couple of facts
38
93182
2778
01:47
coming from this database,
39
95960
1145
01:49
and then we'll return to r bigger than g.
40
97105
2074
01:51
So fact number one is that there has been
41
99179
2510
01:53
a big reversal in the ordering of income inequality
42
101689
3051
01:56
between the United States and Europe
43
104740
1905
01:58
over the past century.
44
106645
1755
02:00
So back in 1900, 1910, income inequality was actually
45
108400
3505
02:03
much higher in Europe than in the United States,
46
111905
2265
02:06
whereas today, it is a lot higher in the United States.
47
114170
3110
02:09
So let me be very clear:
48
117280
1666
02:10
The main explanation for this is not r bigger than g.
49
118946
2824
02:13
It has more to do with changing supply and demand
50
121770
3497
02:17
for skill, the race between education and technology,
51
125267
3453
02:20
globalization, probably more unequal access
52
128720
3580
02:24
to skills in the U.S.,
53
132300
1606
02:25
where you have very good, very top universities
54
133906
2587
02:28
but where the bottom part of the educational system
55
136493
2242
02:30
is not as good,
56
138735
765
02:31
so very unequal access to skills,
57
139500
2361
02:33
and also an unprecedented rise
58
141861
1919
02:35
of top managerial compensation of the United States,
59
143780
3020
02:38
which is difficult to account for
just on the basis of education.
60
146800
2850
02:41
So there is more going on here,
61
149650
1954
02:43
but I'm not going to talk too much about this today,
62
151604
2609
02:46
because I want to focus on wealth inequality.
63
154213
2666
02:48
So let me just show you a very simple indicator
64
156879
2981
02:51
about the income inequality part.
65
159860
2350
02:54
So this is the share of total income
66
162210
2454
02:56
going to the top 10 percent.
67
164664
1788
02:58
So you can see that one century ago,
68
166452
2172
03:00
it was between 45 and 50 percent in Europe
69
168624
3577
03:04
and a little bit above 40 percent in the U.S.,
70
172201
2738
03:06
so there was more inequality in Europe.
71
174939
2271
03:09
Then there was a sharp decline
72
177210
2024
03:11
during the first half of the 20th century,
73
179234
2531
03:13
and in the recent decade, you can see that
74
181765
2363
03:16
the U.S. has become more unequal than Europe,
75
184128
3502
03:19
and this is the first fact I just talked about.
76
187630
2670
03:22
Now, the second fact is more about wealth inequality,
77
190300
3911
03:26
and here the central fact is that wealth inequality
78
194211
3090
03:29
is always a lot higher than income inequality,
79
197301
2606
03:31
and also that wealth inequality,
80
199907
2385
03:34
although it has also increased in recent decades,
81
202292
2653
03:36
is still less extreme today
82
204945
1856
03:38
than what it was a century ago,
83
206801
1879
03:40
although the total quantity of wealth
84
208680
2519
03:43
relative to income has now recovered
85
211199
2025
03:45
from the very large shocks
86
213224
1631
03:46
caused by World War I, the Great Depression,
87
214855
2025
03:48
World War II.
88
216880
1219
03:50
So let me show you two graphs
89
218099
2044
03:52
illustrating fact number two and fact number three.
90
220143
2857
03:55
So first, if you look at the level of wealth inequality,
91
223000
4390
03:59
this is the share of total wealth
92
227390
3158
04:02
going to the top 10 percent of wealth holders,
93
230548
2522
04:05
so you can see the same kind of reversal
94
233070
2709
04:07
between the U.S. and Europe that we had before
95
235779
2565
04:10
for income inequality.
96
238344
1676
04:12
So wealth concentration was higher
97
240020
3550
04:15
in Europe than in the U.S. a century ago,
98
243570
2243
04:17
and now it is the opposite.
99
245813
1834
04:19
But you can also show two things:
100
247647
1991
04:21
First, the general level of wealth inequality
101
249638
3701
04:25
is always higher than income inequality.
102
253339
2655
04:27
So remember, for income inequality,
103
255994
2340
04:30
the share going to the top 10 percent
104
258334
2328
04:32
was between 30 and 50 percent of total income,
105
260662
4298
04:36
whereas for wealth, the share is always
106
264960
2812
04:39
between 60 and 90 percent.
107
267772
2059
04:41
Okay, so that's fact number one,
108
269831
1516
04:43
and that's very important for what follows.
109
271347
1926
04:45
Wealth concentration is always
110
273273
1721
04:46
a lot higher than income concentration.
111
274994
1879
04:48
Fact number two is that the rise
112
276873
3386
04:52
in wealth inequality in recent decades
113
280259
2947
04:55
is still not enough to get us back to 1910.
114
283206
4286
04:59
So the big difference today,
115
287492
1777
05:01
wealth inequality is still very large,
116
289269
1913
05:03
with 60, 70 percent of total wealth for the top 10,
117
291182
3262
05:06
but the good news is that it's actually
118
294444
1845
05:08
better than one century ago,
119
296289
1781
05:10
where you had 90 percent in
Europe going to the top 10.
120
298070
3371
05:13
So today what you have
121
301441
1991
05:15
is what I call the middle 40 percent,
122
303432
2002
05:17
the people who are not in the top 10
123
305434
1913
05:19
and who are not in the bottom 50,
124
307347
1773
05:21
and what you can view as the wealth middle class
125
309120
2266
05:23
that owns 20 to 30 percent
126
311386
3143
05:26
of total wealth, national wealth,
127
314529
1862
05:28
whereas they used to be poor, a century ago,
128
316391
3331
05:31
when there was basically no wealth middle class.
129
319722
2618
05:34
So this is an important change,
130
322340
1577
05:35
and it's interesting to see that wealth inequality
131
323917
4615
05:40
has not fully recovered to pre-World War I levels,
132
328532
3306
05:43
although the total quantity of wealth has recovered.
133
331838
3509
05:47
Okay? So this is the total value
134
335347
1947
05:49
of wealth relative to income,
135
337294
2216
05:51
and you can see that in particular in Europe,
136
339510
2113
05:53
we are almost back to the pre-World War I level.
137
341623
3860
05:57
So there are really two
138
345483
1845
05:59
different parts of the story here.
139
347328
2531
06:01
One has to do with
140
349859
1119
06:02
the total quantity of wealth that we accumulate,
141
350978
2442
06:05
and there is nothing bad per se, of course,
142
353420
1678
06:07
in accumulating a lot of wealth,
143
355098
1747
06:08
and in particular if it is more diffuse
144
356845
2868
06:11
and less concentrated.
145
359713
1394
06:13
So what we really want to focus on
146
361107
2745
06:15
is the long-run evolution of wealth inequality,
147
363852
2381
06:18
and what's going to happen in the future.
148
366233
2300
06:20
How can we account for the fact that
149
368533
2025
06:22
until World War I, wealth inequality was so high
150
370558
3662
06:26
and, if anything, was rising to even higher levels,
151
374220
3190
06:29
and how can we think about the future?
152
377410
3327
06:32
So let me come to some of the explanations
153
380737
3886
06:36
and speculations about the future.
154
384623
2136
06:38
Let me first say that
155
386759
1595
06:40
probably the best model to explain
156
388354
1987
06:42
why wealth is so much
157
390341
2097
06:44
more concentrated than income
158
392438
2186
06:46
is a dynamic, dynastic model
159
394624
3112
06:49
where individuals have a long horizon
160
397736
2464
06:52
and accumulate wealth for all sorts of reasons.
161
400200
2756
06:54
If people were accumulating wealth
162
402956
2610
06:57
only for life cycle reasons,
163
405566
2003
06:59
you know, to be able to consume
164
407569
2013
07:01
when they are old,
165
409582
1587
07:03
then the level of wealth inequality
166
411169
2373
07:05
should be more or less in line
167
413542
2317
07:07
with the level of income inequality.
168
415859
1969
07:09
But it will be very difficult to explain
169
417828
1928
07:11
why you have so much more wealth inequality
170
419756
2194
07:13
than income inequality
171
421950
1484
07:15
with a pure life cycle model,
172
423434
1276
07:16
so you need a story
173
424710
2031
07:18
where people also care
174
426741
1688
07:20
about wealth accumulation for other reasons.
175
428429
2531
07:22
So typically, they want to transmit
176
430960
1924
07:24
wealth to the next generation, to their children,
177
432884
3326
07:28
or sometimes they want to accumulate wealth
178
436210
1768
07:29
because of the prestige, the
power that goes with wealth.
179
437978
2768
07:32
So there must be other reasons
180
440746
1384
07:34
for accumulating wealth than just life cycle
181
442130
1990
07:36
to explain what we see in the data.
182
444120
2768
07:38
Now, in a large class of dynamic models
183
446888
3346
07:42
of wealth accumulation
184
450234
1976
07:44
with such dynastic motive for accumulating wealth,
185
452210
3558
07:47
you will have all sorts of random,
186
455768
2846
07:50
multiplicative shocks.
187
458614
923
07:51
So for instance, some families
188
459537
2249
07:53
have a very large number of children,
189
461786
1687
07:55
so the wealth will be divided.
190
463473
1766
07:57
Some families have fewer children.
191
465239
1890
07:59
You also have shocks to rates of return.
192
467129
2228
08:01
Some families make huge capital gains.
193
469357
2097
08:03
Some made bad investments.
194
471454
1795
08:05
So you will always have some mobility
195
473249
2241
08:07
in the wealth process.
196
475490
1438
08:08
Some people will move up,
some people will move down.
197
476928
2375
08:11
The important point is that,
198
479303
1652
08:12
in any such model,
199
480955
1010
08:13
for a given variance of such shocks,
200
481965
2556
08:16
the equilibrium level of wealth inequality
201
484521
2036
08:18
will be a steeply rising function of r minus g.
202
486557
4837
08:23
And intuitively, the reason why the difference
203
491394
2869
08:26
between the rate of return to wealth
204
494263
1844
08:28
and the growth rate is important
205
496107
1755
08:29
is that initial wealth inequalities
206
497862
2312
08:32
will be amplified at a faster pace
207
500174
2391
08:34
with a bigger r minus g.
208
502565
2069
08:36
So take a simple example,
209
504634
1474
08:38
with r equals five percent and g equals one percent,
210
506108
3766
08:41
wealth holders only need to reinvest
211
509874
2108
08:43
one fifth of their capital income to ensure
212
511982
2639
08:46
that their wealth rises as fast
213
514621
2733
08:49
as the size of the economy.
214
517354
1913
08:51
So this makes it easier
215
519267
1383
08:52
to build and perpetuate large fortunes
216
520650
1766
08:54
because you can consume four fifths,
217
522416
1955
08:56
assuming zero tax,
218
524371
1739
08:58
and you can just reinvest one fifth.
219
526110
1661
08:59
So of course some families
will consume more than that,
220
527771
2588
09:02
some will consume less, so there will be
221
530359
1743
09:04
some mobility in the distribution,
222
532102
1755
09:05
but on average, they only need to reinvest one fifth,
223
533857
2846
09:08
so this allows high wealth inequalities to be sustained.
224
536703
3769
09:12
Now, you should not be surprised
225
540472
2497
09:14
by the statement that r can be bigger than g forever,
226
542969
3536
09:18
because, in fact, this is what happened
227
546505
1616
09:20
during most of the history of mankind.
228
548121
2071
09:22
And this was in a way very obvious to everybody
229
550192
3351
09:25
for a simple reason, which is that growth
230
553543
1778
09:27
was close to zero percent
231
555321
2188
09:29
during most of the history of mankind.
232
557509
1621
09:31
Growth was maybe 0.1, 0.2, 0.3 percent,
233
559130
3532
09:34
but very slow growth of population
234
562662
1996
09:36
and output per capita,
235
564658
1997
09:38
whereas the rate of return on capital
236
566655
1884
09:40
of course was not zero percent.
237
568539
1856
09:42
It was, for land assets, which was
238
570395
2036
09:44
the traditional form
239
572431
1809
09:46
of assets in preindustrial societies,
240
574240
2401
09:48
it was typically five percent.
241
576641
1763
09:50
Any reader of Jane Austen would know that.
242
578404
3786
09:54
If you want an annual income of 1,000 pounds,
243
582190
2908
09:57
you should have a capital value
244
585098
1642
09:58
of 20,000 pounds so that
245
586740
1856
10:00
five percent of 20,000 is 1,000.
246
588596
2550
10:03
And in a way, this was
247
591146
2017
10:05
the very foundation of society,
248
593163
1778
10:06
because r bigger than g
249
594941
3035
10:09
was what allowed holders of wealth and assets
250
597976
4124
10:14
to live off their capital income
251
602100
2690
10:16
and to do something else in life
252
604790
2700
10:19
than just to care about their own survival.
253
607490
3195
10:22
Now, one important conclusion
254
610685
2160
10:24
of my historical research is that
255
612845
1991
10:26
modern industrial growth did not change
256
614836
2711
10:29
this basic fact as much as one might have expected.
257
617547
2824
10:32
Of course, the growth rate
258
620371
1679
10:34
following the Industrial Revolution
259
622050
1808
10:35
rose, typically from zero to one to two percent,
260
623858
4322
10:40
but at the same time, the rate of return
261
628180
1930
10:42
to capital also rose
262
630110
1645
10:43
so that the gap between the two
263
631755
2425
10:46
did not really change.
264
634180
1456
10:47
So during the 20th century,
265
635636
2250
10:49
you had a very unique combination of events.
266
637886
2644
10:52
First, a very low rate of return
267
640530
2017
10:54
due to the 1914 and 1945 war shocks,
268
642547
3016
10:57
destruction of wealth, inflation,
269
645563
2305
10:59
bankruptcy during the Great Depression,
270
647868
1980
11:01
and all of this reduced
271
649848
1665
11:03
the private rate of return to wealth
272
651513
1750
11:05
to unusually low levels
273
653263
1895
11:07
between 1914 and 1945.
274
655158
2339
11:09
And then, in the postwar period,
275
657497
1836
11:11
you had unusually high growth rate,
276
659333
3237
11:14
partly due to the reconstruction.
277
662570
2374
11:16
You know, in Germany, in France, in Japan,
278
664944
1925
11:18
you had five percent growth rate
279
666869
1551
11:20
between 1950 and 1980
280
668420
3150
11:23
largely due to reconstruction,
281
671570
1643
11:25
and also due to very large demographic growth,
282
673213
2351
11:27
the Baby Boom Cohort effect.
283
675564
2141
11:29
Now, apparently that's not going to last for very long,
284
677705
2438
11:32
or at least the population growth
285
680143
1675
11:33
is supposed to decline in the future,
286
681818
2768
11:36
and the best projections we have is that
287
684586
3656
11:40
the long-run growth is going to be closer
288
688242
1828
11:42
to one to two percent
289
690070
1423
11:43
rather than four to five percent.
290
691493
1946
11:45
So if you look at this,
291
693439
2677
11:48
these are the best estimates we have
292
696116
2141
11:50
of world GDP growth
293
698257
1656
11:51
and rate of return on capital,
294
699913
2359
11:54
average rates of return on capital,
295
702272
2088
11:56
so you can see that during most
296
704360
1068
11:57
of the history of mankind,
297
705428
1517
11:58
the growth rate was very small,
298
706945
1613
12:00
much lower than the rate of return,
299
708558
1834
12:02
and then during the 20th century,
300
710392
2362
12:04
it is really the population growth,
301
712754
2171
12:06
very high in the postwar period,
302
714925
2272
12:09
and the reconstruction process
303
717197
1600
12:10
that brought growth
304
718797
1573
12:12
to a smaller gap with the rate of return.
305
720370
3071
12:15
Here I use the United Nations population projections,
306
723441
3523
12:18
so of course they are uncertain.
307
726964
2476
12:21
It could be that we all start
308
729440
1391
12:22
having a lot of children in the future,
309
730831
2106
12:24
and the growth rates are going to be higher,
310
732937
2765
12:27
but from now on,
311
735702
1249
12:28
these are the best projections we have,
312
736951
2802
12:31
and this will make global growth
313
739753
1934
12:33
decline and the gap between
314
741687
2756
12:36
the rate of return go up.
315
744443
2003
12:38
Now, the other unusual event
316
746446
2862
12:41
during the 20th century
317
749308
1671
12:42
was, as I said,
318
750979
1329
12:44
destruction, taxation of capital,
319
752308
2316
12:46
so this is the pre-tax rate of return.
320
754624
2735
12:49
This is the after-tax rate of return,
321
757359
2979
12:52
and after destruction,
322
760338
1566
12:53
and this is what brought
323
761904
1777
12:55
the average rate of return
324
763681
1688
12:57
after tax, after destruction,
325
765369
1789
12:59
below the growth rate during a long time period.
326
767158
2420
13:01
But without the destruction,
327
769578
1674
13:03
without the taxation, this
would not have happened.
328
771252
2475
13:05
So let me say that the balance between
329
773727
3243
13:08
returns on capital and growth
330
776970
2356
13:11
depends on many different factors
331
779326
1862
13:13
that are very difficult to predict:
332
781188
2085
13:15
technology and the development
333
783273
2115
13:17
of capital-intensive techniques.
334
785388
2584
13:19
So right now, the most capital-intensive sectors
335
787972
3019
13:22
in the economy are the real estate sector, housing,
336
790991
3376
13:26
the energy sector, but it could be in the future
337
794367
2862
13:29
that we have a lot more robots in a number of sectors
338
797229
3712
13:32
and that this would be a bigger share
339
800941
1889
13:34
of the total capital stock that it is today.
340
802830
1910
13:36
Well, we are very far from this,
341
804740
1994
13:38
and from now, what's going on
342
806734
1766
13:40
in the real estate sector, the energy sector,
343
808500
1789
13:42
is much more important for the total capital stock
344
810289
2126
13:44
and capital share.
345
812415
1134
13:45
The other important issue
346
813549
2033
13:47
is that there are scale effects
in portfolio management,
347
815582
2150
13:49
together with financial complexity,
348
817732
2419
13:52
financial deregulation,
349
820151
1450
13:53
that make it easier to get higher rates of return
350
821601
2709
13:56
for a large portfolio,
351
824310
1627
13:57
and this seems to be particularly strong
352
825937
2663
14:00
for billionaires, large capital endowments.
353
828600
1982
14:02
Just to give you one example,
354
830582
2290
14:04
this comes from the Forbes billionaire rankings
355
832872
3333
14:08
over the 1987-2013 period,
356
836205
3330
14:11
and you can see the very top wealth holders
357
839535
2788
14:14
have been going up at six, seven percent per year
358
842323
3117
14:17
in real terms above inflation,
359
845440
2391
14:19
whereas average income in the world,
360
847831
2372
14:22
average wealth in the world,
361
850203
1363
14:23
have increased at only two percent per year.
362
851566
3383
14:26
And you find the same
363
854949
1729
14:28
for large university endowments —
364
856678
1276
14:29
the bigger the initial endowments,
365
857954
2268
14:32
the bigger the rate of return.
366
860222
2068
14:34
Now, what could be done?
367
862290
1678
14:35
The first thing is that I think we need
368
863968
2396
14:38
more financial transparency.
369
866364
2115
14:40
We know too little about global wealth dynamics,
370
868479
3841
14:44
so we need international transmission
371
872320
1900
14:46
of bank information.
372
874220
1262
14:47
We need a global registry of financial assets,
373
875482
2686
14:50
more coordination on wealth taxation,
374
878168
2491
14:52
and even wealth tax with a small tax rate
375
880659
3112
14:55
will be a way to produce information
376
883771
2216
14:57
so that then we can adapt our policies
377
885987
2682
15:00
to whatever we observe.
378
888669
1836
15:02
And to some extent, the fight
379
890505
1838
15:04
against tax havens
380
892343
1481
15:05
and automatic transmission of information
381
893824
1815
15:07
is pushing us in this direction.
382
895639
1851
15:09
Now, there are other ways to redistribute wealth,
383
897490
2324
15:11
which it can be tempting to use.
384
899814
2957
15:14
Inflation:
385
902771
1356
15:16
it's much easier to print money
386
904127
1699
15:17
than to write a tax code, so that's very tempting,
387
905826
2155
15:19
but sometimes you don't know
what you do with the money.
388
907981
2120
15:22
This is a problem.
389
910101
1647
15:23
Expropriation is very tempting.
390
911748
1863
15:25
Just when you feel some people get too wealthy,
391
913611
2261
15:27
you just expropriate them.
392
915872
1294
15:29
But this is not a very efficient way
393
917166
1712
15:30
to organize a regulation of wealth dynamics.
394
918878
2833
15:33
So war is an even less efficient way,
395
921711
2479
15:36
so I tend to prefer progressive taxation,
396
924190
2336
15:38
but of course, history — (Laughter) —
397
926526
2574
15:41
history will invent its own best ways,
398
929100
1735
15:42
and it will probably involve
399
930835
1698
15:44
a combination of all of these.
400
932533
1734
15:46
Thank you.
401
934267
1866
15:48
(Applause)
402
936133
2137
15:50
Bruno Giussani: Thomas Piketty. Thank you.
403
938270
5559
15:55
Thomas, I want to ask you two or three questions,
404
943829
1879
15:57
because it's impressive how you're
in command of your data, of course,
405
945708
3859
16:01
but basically what you suggest is
406
949567
3794
16:05
growing wealth concentration is kind of
407
953361
1573
16:06
a natural tendency of capitalism,
408
954934
1924
16:08
and if we leave it to its own devices,
409
956858
3538
16:12
it may threaten the system itself,
410
960396
2240
16:14
so you're suggesting that we need to act
411
962636
1726
16:16
to implement policies that redistribute wealth,
412
964362
3038
16:19
including the ones we just saw:
413
967400
1721
16:21
progressive taxation, etc.
414
969121
1471
16:22
In the current political context,
415
970592
2139
16:24
how realistic are those?
416
972731
1991
16:26
How likely do you think that it is
417
974722
1811
16:28
that they will be implemented?
418
976533
1744
16:30
Thomas Piketty: Well, you know, I think
419
978277
1211
16:31
if you look back through time,
420
979488
1781
16:33
the history of income, wealth and taxation
421
981269
2651
16:35
is full of surprise.
422
983920
1602
16:37
So I am not terribly impressed
423
985522
2605
16:40
by those who know in advance
424
988127
1568
16:41
what will or will not happen.
425
989695
1631
16:43
I think one century ago,
426
991326
1704
16:45
many people would have said
427
993030
1569
16:46
that progressive income taxation would never happen
428
994599
2138
16:48
and then it happened.
429
996737
1520
16:50
And even five years ago,
430
998257
1989
16:52
many people would have said that bank secrecy
431
1000246
2352
16:54
will be with us forever in Switzerland,
432
1002598
2025
16:56
that Switzerland was too powerful
433
1004623
1788
16:58
for the rest of the world,
434
1006411
1489
16:59
and then suddenly it took a few U.S. sanctions
435
1007900
2961
17:02
against Swiss banks for a big change to happen,
436
1010861
2622
17:05
and now we are moving toward
437
1013483
1703
17:07
more financial transparency.
438
1015186
1676
17:08
So I think it's not that difficult
439
1016862
4281
17:13
to better coordinate politically.
440
1021143
2469
17:15
We are going to have a treaty
441
1023612
2058
17:17
with half of the world GDP around the table
442
1025670
3049
17:20
with the U.S. and the European Union,
443
1028719
2002
17:22
so if half of the world GDP is not enough
444
1030721
2126
17:24
to make progress on financial transparency
445
1032847
2666
17:27
and minimal tax for multinational corporate profits,
446
1035513
4084
17:31
what does it take?
447
1039597
1664
17:33
So I think these are not technical difficulties.
448
1041261
3623
17:36
I think we can make progress
449
1044884
1924
17:38
if we have a more pragmatic
approach to these questions
450
1046808
2587
17:41
and we have the proper sanctions
451
1049395
1901
17:43
on those who benefit from financial opacity.
452
1051296
2991
17:46
BG: One of the arguments
453
1054287
1653
17:47
against your point of view
454
1055940
1433
17:49
is that economic inequality
455
1057373
1442
17:50
is not only a feature of capitalism
but is actually one of its engines.
456
1058815
3637
17:54
So we take measures to lower inequality,
457
1062452
2801
17:57
and at the same time we lower growth, potentially.
458
1065253
2407
17:59
What do you answer to that?
459
1067660
1560
18:01
TP: Yeah, I think inequality
460
1069220
1729
18:02
is not a problem per se.
461
1070949
1889
18:04
I think inequality up to a point
462
1072838
2040
18:06
can actually be useful for innovation and growth.
463
1074878
2652
18:09
The problem is, it's a question of degree.
464
1077530
2193
18:11
When inequality gets too extreme,
465
1079723
2544
18:14
then it becomes useless for growth
466
1082267
2889
18:17
and it can even become bad
467
1085156
1462
18:18
because it tends to lead to high perpetuation
468
1086618
3057
18:21
of inequality over time
469
1089675
1636
18:23
and low mobility.
470
1091311
1866
18:25
And for instance, the kind of wealth concentrations
471
1093177
3286
18:28
that we had in the 19th century
472
1096463
2877
18:31
and pretty much until World War I
473
1099340
1925
18:33
in every European country
474
1101265
1765
18:35
was, I think, not useful for growth.
475
1103030
2094
18:37
This was destroyed by a combination
476
1105124
2102
18:39
of tragic events and policy changes,
477
1107226
2341
18:41
and this did not prevent growth from happening.
478
1109567
2272
18:43
And also, extreme inequality can be bad
479
1111839
3443
18:47
for our democratic institutions
480
1115282
2198
18:49
if it creates very unequal access to political voice,
481
1117480
2383
18:51
and the influence of private money
482
1119863
1865
18:53
in U.S. politics, I think,
483
1121728
2002
18:55
is a matter of concern right now.
484
1123730
2540
18:58
So we don't want to return to that kind of extreme,
485
1126270
3076
19:01
pre-World War I inequality.
486
1129346
2090
19:03
Having a decent share of the national wealth
487
1131436
3674
19:07
for the middle class is not bad for growth.
488
1135110
3390
19:10
It is actually useful
489
1138500
1281
19:11
both for equity and efficiency reasons.
490
1139781
3084
19:14
BG: I said at the beginning
491
1142865
1665
19:16
that your book has been criticized.
492
1144530
2109
19:18
Some of your data has been criticized.
493
1146639
1241
19:19
Some of your choice of data sets has been criticized.
494
1147880
2466
19:22
You have been accused of cherry-picking data
495
1150346
1876
19:24
to make your case. What do you answer to that?
496
1152222
2737
19:26
TP: Well, I answer that I am very happy
497
1154959
1927
19:28
that this book is stimulating debate.
498
1156886
2467
19:31
This is part of what it is intended for.
499
1159353
2481
19:33
Look, the reason why I put all the data online
500
1161834
3294
19:37
with all of the detailed computation
501
1165128
1846
19:38
is so that we can have
an open and transparent
502
1166974
2334
19:41
debate about this.
503
1169308
1669
19:42
So I have responded point by point
504
1170977
1766
19:44
to every concern.
505
1172743
1792
19:46
Let me say that if I was to rewrite the book today,
506
1174535
3113
19:49
I would actually conclude
507
1177648
1541
19:51
that the rise in wealth inequality,
508
1179189
2194
19:53
particularly in the United States,
509
1181383
1927
19:55
has been actually higher
than what I report in my book.
510
1183310
2373
19:57
There is a recent study by Saez and Zucman
511
1185683
3245
20:00
showing, with new data
512
1188928
1592
20:02
which I didn't have at the time of the book,
513
1190520
1777
20:04
that wealth concentration in the U.S. has risen
514
1192297
2527
20:06
even more than what I report.
515
1194824
1936
20:08
And there will be other data in the future.
516
1196760
2031
20:10
Some of it will go in different directions.
517
1198791
2151
20:12
Look, we put online almost every week
518
1200942
4099
20:17
new, updated series on the
World Top Income Database
519
1205041
2934
20:19
and we will keep doing so in the future,
520
1207975
1900
20:21
in particular in emerging countries,
521
1209875
2306
20:24
and I welcome all of those who want to contribute
522
1212181
2929
20:27
to this data collection process.
523
1215110
2346
20:29
In fact, I certainly agree
524
1217456
2808
20:32
that there is not enough
525
1220264
1614
20:33
transparency about wealth dynamics,
526
1221878
1878
20:35
and a good way to have better data
527
1223756
1915
20:37
would be to have a wealth tax
528
1225671
1865
20:39
with a small tax rate to begin with
529
1227536
1571
20:41
so that we can all agree
530
1229107
2339
20:43
about this important evolution
531
1231446
1564
20:45
and adapt our policies to whatever we observe.
532
1233010
3327
20:48
So taxation is a source of knowledge,
533
1236337
2062
20:50
and that's what we need the most right now.
534
1238399
2936
20:53
BG: Thomas Piketty, merci beaucoup.
535
1241335
1815
20:55
Thank you.
TP: Thank you. (Applause)
536
1243150
4000

▲Back to top

ABOUT THE SPEAKER
Thomas Piketty - Economist
Thomas Piketty is an economist and professor at the Paris School of Economics. His 2014 book, "Capital in the Twenty-first Century," caused a sensation upon publication.

Why you should listen
Is the global economy accelerating toward a future that’s incompatible with democracy? In this provocative talk about inequality and wealth, economist Thomas Piketty provides new context for his groundbreaking book, Capital in the Twenty-First Century.
More profile about the speaker
Thomas Piketty | Speaker | TED.com

Data provided by TED.

This site was created in May 2015 and the last update was on January 12, 2020. It will no longer be updated.

We are currently creating a new site called "eng.lish.video" and would be grateful if you could access it.

If you have any questions or suggestions, please feel free to write comments in your language on the contact form.

Privacy Policy

Developer's Blog

Buy Me A Coffee